Inflation obsession persists, year after year

Opinion: ‘Sado-monetarism,’ is very much alive today

Inflation obsessives  failed to understand that printing money in a depressed economy isn’t inflationary. Photograph: PA
Inflation obsessives failed to understand that printing money in a depressed economy isn’t inflationary. Photograph: PA

Recently the Federal Reserve released transcripts of its monetary policy meetings during the fateful year of 2008. And boy, are they discouraging reading.

Partly that’s because Fed officials come across as essentially clueless about the gathering economic storm. But we knew that already. What’s really striking is the extent to which they were obsessed with the wrong thing. The economy was plunging, yet all many people at the Fed wanted to talk about was inflation.

Matthew O'Brien at The Atlantic has done the math. In August 2008 there were 322 mentions of inflation, versus only 28 of unemployment and 19 of systemic risks or crises. In the meeting on September 16th, 2008 – the day after Lehman fell! – there were 129 mentions of inflation, versus 26 mentions of unemployment and only four of systemic risks or crises.

Historians of the Great Depression have long marvelled at the folly of policy discussion at the time. For example, the Bank of England, faced with a devastating deflationary spiral, kept obsessing over the imagined threat of inflation. As the economist Ralph Hawtrey famously observed, “That was to cry ‘Fire, fire!’ in Noah’s flood.” But it turns out that modern monetary officials facing financial crisis were just as obsessed with the wrong thing as their predecessors three generations earlier.

READ MORE

And it wasn't just a bad call in 2008. Much supposedly informed opinion has remained fixated on the supposed threat of rising prices despite being wrong again and again. If you spent the last five years watching CNBC, or reading the Wall Street Journal opinion pages, or listening to prominent conservative economists, you lived in a constant state of alarm over runaway inflation, which was coming any day now. It never did.


Influence
What accounts for inflation obsession? One answer is that obsessives failed to distinguish between underlying inflation and short-term fluctuations in the headline number, which are mainly driven by volatile energy and food prices. Gas prices, in particular, strongly influence inflation in any given year, and dire warnings are heard whenever prices rise at the pump; yet such blips say nothing at all about future inflation. They also failed to understand that printing money in a depressed economy isn't inflationary. But maybe there was some excuse for not grasping this point in 2008 or early 2009. The point, however, is that inflation obsession has persisted, year after year, even as events have refuted its supposed justifications. And this tells us that something more than bad analysis is at work. At a fundamental level, it's political.

This is fairly obvious if you look at who the inflation obsessives are. While a few conservatives believe that the Fed should be doing more, not less, they have little if any real influence. The overall picture is that most conservatives are inflation obsessives, and nearly all inflation obsessives are conservative.


Private sector
Why is this the case? In part it reflects the belief that the government should never seek to mitigate economic pain, because the private sector always knows best. Back in the 1930s, Austrian economists like Friedrich Hayek and Joseph Schumpeter inveighed against any effort to fight the depression with easy money; to do so, warned Schumpeter, would be to leave "the work of depressions undone". Modern conservatives are generally less open about the harshness of their view, but it's pretty much the same.

The flip side of this anti-government attitude is the conviction that any attempt to boost the economy, whether fiscal or monetary, must produce disastrous results – Zimbabwe, here we come! And this conviction is so strong it persists no matter how wrong it has been.

Finally, all this ties in with a predilection for acting tough and inflicting punishment whatever the economic conditions. The British journalist, William Keegan, once described this as “sado-monetarism,” and it’s very much alive today. Does any of this matter? It’s true that the Fed hasn’t surrendered to the sado-monetarists. But I’d argue that the clamour from inflation obsessives has intimidated the Fed, which might otherwise have done more.

As I suggested, we used to marvel at the wrongheadedness of policymakers during the Great Depression. But when the Great Recession struck, and we were given a chance to do better, we ended up repeating all the same mistakes.